Sections

Services

Information

UK United Kingdom

Tasmania election: what is the Hare-Clark system?

After trading blows around predictable topics, the only issue of consensus in a recent televised debate between the leaders of the Tasmanian Liberal and Labor parties, Will Hodgman and Lara Giddings, was…

Liberal leader Will Hodgman casts his vote in the 2010 Tasmanian election. But just how is Tasmania’s lower house elected? AAP/Julian Smith

After trading blows around predictable topics, the only issue of consensus in a recent televised debate between the leaders of the Tasmanian Liberal and Labor parties, Will Hodgman and Lara Giddings, was that minority government is not an option ahead of this Saturday’s state election.

Perhaps to emphasise this stance, members of other parties were excluded from the debate. This is despite the Greens sitting just 5.4% behind Labor in a recent poll and expectations the Palmer United Party will pick up one or possibly two seats, depending on the flow of preferences.

The reason minor parties – and the associated prospect of minority government – represent such a realistic threat in Tasmania is the Hare-Clark system that is used to elect the state’s lower house.

Under the system as it applies in Tasmania, there are five electorates which elect five members each. To be elected a candidate requires enough votes to fill a “quota”, or 16.67% of the vote. Candidates who do not gain a quota have their votes redistributed according to preferences. Candidates who receive more than a full quota also have their excess votes redistributed. The process continues until all five positions are filled.

The Hare-Clark system

Driven by the failure of a number of progressive bills relating to female suffrage, referendum and disenfranchisement, Andrew Inglis Clark, who introduced the system to Tasmania as state attorney-general, saw electoral reform as a way to modernise a staid and conservative Tasmanian establishment in the early 20th century.

Philosopher John Stuart Mill also supported the system, first devised by British political scientist Thomas Hare. Mill believed that proportional parliamentary reform would stop the defect that enabled:

…the strongest party to exclude all weaker parties from making their opinions heard in the assembly of the nation.

Complex but fair

Hare-Clark often invites criticism because of its complex counting process, but the basics are clear.

A number of factors are designed to reduce the influence of parties and factions becoming too powerful. There is no ticketed voting, so candidates are usually elected as a consequence of name and local visibility rather than party.

This also has the less useful effect of embedding low-level dynastic politics. For example, the current House of Assembly has a brother and sister combination and two sons of former premiers, while Hodgman’s father, uncle and grandfather were all members of Tasmanian parliament.

Party influence is further mitigated by a ban on how-to-vote cards, which places the burden of decision-making on the voter rather than party preferences. This can lead to peculiar outcomes, for example allowing 27-year-old Rebecca White to defeat 24-year Labor veteran David Llewellyn in 2010.

Highly representative

Hare-Clark is also highly representative. In the 2011 New South Wales state election, for example, parties and candidates outside the big three parties (Liberal, Labor and the Nationals) obtained 23.3% of the primary vote for a total of four seats out of 93 with its single member district system. The National Party gained only 12.6% of the primary vote, yet won 18 seats.

However, in the 2010 Tasmanian state election, the Greens received 21.3% of the popular vote and 20% of seats (five), while the Liberals received 39% of the vote and 40% of the seats (ten). Labor won 36.9% and the same number of seats as the Liberals.

The Tasmanian Greens, under Nick McKim, won 21.3% of the vote in 2010, translating to 20% (or five) lower house seats. AAP/Patrick Caruana

Minority governments are often successful

An argument for majority party government is that minorities can wield disproportionate power. This is a weak argument. Few concessions have been made in Tasmania over the past 25 years to minority partners.

At the same time, over the past electoral cycle, the Greens were handed difficult ministries (including corrections, human services and education) where they had few ideological differences with Labor. In fact, Greens leader and education minister Nick McKim was a useful tool for Labor to test and absorb unpopular sentiment around school closures.

The paradox of Hare-Clark is best described by political scientist Richard Herr, who says:

Hare-Clark … is more highly supported when it does not achieve its philosophical aims than when it does.

The bottom line is that Hare-Clark works. More symbolically, Hare-Clark is a thoroughly modern system that is highly representative and one that should be admired in the face of rising apathy towards Western electoral practice.

Join the conversation

5 Comments sorted by

  1. Craig Read

    logged in via Twitter

    "Hare-Clark … is more highly supported when it does not achieve its philosophical aims than when it does."

    Funnily enough, I think that also covers most facets of democratic process. I don't think either of the major parties would support something that was truly representative or gave more democratic power to individuals.

    report
  2. Jeremy Culberg

    Electrical Asset Manager at Power Generation

    One of the advantages of the Hare Clark system is that in your electorate, each major party will typically field at least 3 members. You may like whichever party is in power at the time, but dislike one of your local members. So you can vote for another Liberal / Labor representative, thus kicking out the idiot from parliament, whilst keeping your preferred side of politics going. Some years ago, when Tasmania fielded 7 representatives per electorate (rather than 5), this actually happened - the…

    Read more
    1. Brandon Young

      Retired

      In reply to Jeremy Culberg

      Actually that is a good argument - let the voters decide which factions dominate, and which members get up, not the power brokers - might clean up the system pretty quickly. There may be less apathy if people really do have more choice. Pity it will never happen federally - unless alongside a referendum on a republic??

      report
  3. Dennis Alexander

    logged in via LinkedIn

    Minority government is not a threat. A government can get up whatever legislation it can get majority support for in any parliament - a minority government in that respect is no different. Under Hare-Clark, the parliament itself is more representative of the population, and one would think that this is a good thing. But representational notion this goes against the winner-take-all mentality fostered by the major parties and the press since the 1950s. The fact that a recent federal parliament was effectively hijacked by an obstreperous opposition and a hostile (which was both their rights) does not make minority government, in principle, any less effective or stable than majority government. However, minority governments do have a hard time imposing ideological positions on populations against the weight of evidence -and sound argument something majority governments of either stripe have had no hesitation in doing in the past.

    report
  4. harry oblong

    tree surgeon

    this system should be national...........true representation for the voters

    report