Menu Close

Analysis reveals economic benefits of legalised cannabis

Have you paid tax on that? prensa420

It is easy to despair of the low quality of public debate on drugs policy in the UK. Some of the loudest voices reflect fixed views and make opportunistic use of any fragment of evidence that happens to support them. The very act of contemplating certain policy options can attract vehement criticism and –- consequently, perhaps –- some policy-makers who, before entering government, had open minds on options for drugs policy, cling firmly to the prohibitionist line when in power.

Few participants in the public debate on drugs policy are prepared to consider the full range of issues involved in policy choice, or acknowledge the large uncertainties that exist in the research evidence. The debate is often conducted in emotive terms, using vague conceptions of “tough” and “liberal” policy, sometimes making large deductive leaps that have little backing in logic.

Cannabis is the most widely used illicit drug in Britain (the research reported here all relates to England and Wales rather than Great Britain or the UK). Although its use has been in slow decline for over a decade, survey evidence still suggests that there may be as many as 3.4m users (down from 5.5m in 2006), more than all other illegal drugs combined.

UK policy is prohibitionist: the users and suppliers of cannabis are threatened with maximum sentences of five and 14 years imprisonment respectively. We currently imprison more than 2,000 people a year for cannabis offences, despite the lack of any clear empirical evidence of an effect of enforcement activity on cannabis use.

Trends in custodial sentences for cannabis offences and cannabis use.

This prohibitionist policy is dictated by international treaty provisions and aspirations which found expression in a remarkably implausible UN slogan: “a drug-free world – we can do it!”

Would regulation work?

A recent report co-authored with Mark Bryan and Emilia Del Bono considers one radical policy option –- a system of licensed, regulated and taxed cannabis supply.

We identify no fewer than 17 possible consequences that need to be evaluated before arriving at an informed and balanced view on the case for this reform. They include: savings in various policing and criminal justice costs; changes in cannabis-related crime, accidents, dependency, mental and physical illness, productivity, and the scarring effects of a criminal record.

Cost-benefit analysis can be used to put all projected consequences of reform –- both monetary and non-monetary -– on a common cash-equivalent basis. This gives us a coherent overall view of the arguments and some idea of which particular consequences might be crucial in tilting things one way or the other.

We evaluate only the effect of the reform on the social costs imposed by cannabis users on the rest of society and we are able to make estimates of the net social effects of reform for 13 of the 17 items on our list of possible consequences.

There are large uncertainties in evaluating the costs and benefits of reform. The first is what a legalised market would look like. The US model of legalisation leads to a large numbers of suppliers and different products that is hard to regulate. Other models, like the extreme case of a government monopoly proposed for Uruguay, entail fewer, larger licensed suppliers operating under tight product controls.

The possibility of product regulation is one of the strongest arguments for legalisation. The primary psychoactive component of cannabis is D9-tetrahydrocannabinol (THC), which has been linked to impaired brain function and psychotic symptoms, but research suggests that another component, cannabidiol (CBD) has a protective anti-psychotic effect. In the last decade or so, there has been a worrying rise in the market share of high-THC, low-CBD forms of cannabis (usually known as “skunk”), and this worrying trend has proved impossible to control under prohibitionist policy.

A second major source of uncertainty is the nature of demand. It has not proved possible to arrive at a clear understanding of the reasons for the slow decline in cannabis use or the shift towards higher-potency product. There is also no research consensus on price effects, especially the cross-effects of variation in cannabis prices on the demand for alcohol, tobacco and other drugs.

A third difficulty is in identifying the true causal relationship between cannabis use and eventual long-term harms.

So what’s the cost (or benefit)?

Given these uncertainties, we considered three possible outcomes based on differing levels of cannabis demand after legalisation. A “low response”, where cannabis use barely increases; a “high response” scenario, where usage increases a great deal; and a “mid response”.

We assume a significant degree of product regulation, with government setting excise taxes at a rate comparable with those used in the alcohol and tobacco markets. We also assume a residual illegal supply with a market share rather larger than the share of illegal supply in the tobacco market at present.

Projected net social benefit of reform under three demand response scenarios.

The striking feature of these estimates is how small the projected costs and benefits are. This is partly because we are only considering costs and benefits to non-users. The anticipated costs to cannabis users themselves (health risks, for instance) are necessarily outweighed by the anticipated enjoyment of consumption.

But it is also partly because the plausible scale of cost savings (reduced enforcement costs) and cost increases (medical care, crime victimisation) to society appear to be inherently modest. There is no compelling evidence for a huge impact –- either good or bad –- on the rest of society from the changes in cannabis use likely to be produced by legalisation.

A possible exception to this is cannabis-related crime. Although we find very little evidence that cannabis use causes any crime at all, the large size of the market means that costs could be high under the most pessimistic “high response” scenario. But the large projected net increase in cannabis-related crime in that case (almost £600m) is highly uncertain, with a margin of error of plus or minus £800m.

By far the largest projected impact relates to the government budget. Under this reform, government gains additional tax revenue from licensed supply and makes net savings on policing and criminal justice costs. Since taxes represent transfers within society rather than gains to society, the improvement in the government’s budgetary position is not a strong argument for reform in principle, but it might be an attractive feature of reform to governments in practice.

Projected gains to the government budget.

There is nothing in these findings that should frighten any government –- there is no “killer fact” that makes legalisation unthinkable. While there is a significant possibility of net social harm if the demand response to policy change turned out to be extremely high, close monitoring of prevalence would allow the policy to be evaluated in practice and reversed if necessary.

A version of this article first appeared at Society Central.

Want to write?

Write an article and join a growing community of more than 180,400 academics and researchers from 4,911 institutions.

Register now